Raghuram G. Rajan -- Fault lines: How hidden fractures still threaten the world economy ========================================================================================= Like most books on the financial crisis, this one provides both an analysis of what caused the problem and a few suggestions about how to prevent it from happening again. What's a little special about Rajan's analysis is that he attempts to show how the political system is structured so as to almost inevitably produce the results we have seen recently: an asset boom and bust. Rajan repeatedly emphasizes the interplay between consumer driven economies that borrow (the U.S. especially) and export driven economies, some of which lend to the consumers. But, he has little in the way of suggestions on how to make them change. Telling them to grow up, to act responsibly, and to engage in some shared sacrifice will not cause any changes. Rajan spends a bit of time talking about the rising inequality of wealth in the U.S. and a few of its consequences, e.g. unequal access to education. But, in a political system that has become increasingly partisan, we are not likely to see much balancing of income and wealth. At both the state and the federal level, no one seems willing to compromise, let alone sacrifice. Increases in taxes, for example, are blocked. And, the idea of a more progressive tax system seems out of the question. Rajan is especially good at explaining how the political system in the U.S., which is unable to make sustainable improvement to the stagnant incomes of middle class Americans, has settled for unsustainable fixes, e.g. the extension of ever more easy credit. Increasing debt in lieu of increasing incomes, whether in the way of home mortgages (and refinancing, and equity mortgages) or credit cards debt, can only be a short-term solution, as we've recently found out. But, in a society where no one is willing to give up anything for the good of the whole, there are possibly no alternatives. Rajan is also good at showing how our political system is effective at giving us what we want, or what *someone* wants, even when that's not what we need in the long term. The extension of massive amounts of credit and debt in the years prior to the financial crisis is an example. That was done during both Republican and Democratic administrations of the U.S. federal government. We'd like to blame the Federal Reserve Board and Alan Greenspan for allowing that loose lending to happen, and we should blame him, but he was pressured by members of Congress to do so, and that is not likely to change, no matter who is head of the Fed. It's significant, I believe that Rajan's main attempt at prescribing solutions is a chapter on improving our education systems and on increasing and broadening access to education. We need both, but that's stating the obvious. And, it's not likely that our political system is going improve much with respect to education. However, I suspect that he proposes fixes to our education systems because he believes that a capitalist-democratic system cannot be fixed. Such a system responds to the wishes and pressures of constituents, voters, campaign contributors, pressure groups, lobbyists, etc. After all, that is what a democratic system is designed to do. But, by doing so, it will inevitably drift toward instability: increased leverage, higher risk, faster transactions, closer tolerance, tighter couplings, and tighter connections. And, now, apparently, it will also drift toward looser regulation and less over-sight. We should expect to see more of the fault lines and the booms, busts, and crises that Rajan describes. And, as far as improvements to our education systems as a fix, I'm very much in favor of improving schools and broadening access to higher education. But, I don't think we should be fooled into thinking that this is a fix for everything. In particular, some of us are more capable of making use of higher education than others, just as some of us are more capable of being reliable workers, or physically strong workers, or skilled craftsmen, or excellent artists. But, if we shift toward an economy in which only the highly educated are capable of earning a decent standard of living (doing so by sending all non-skilled jobs overseas), then lots of us will not be able to earn a living. We are likely to see an even more unequal distribution of income and wealth. That's terrible for those who can't compete for those jobs that require high levels of education and knowledge, and it is terrible for our economy, because not enough of us will be able to afford to buy the goods and services that will make the economy go. Rajan does explain why some of the cures that we'd think are obvious ones do not work. For example, the Fed's attempts to get the economy moving by keeping interest rates low is made ineffective by the fact that the Fed, whose mandate is only to help the U.S. economy, actually effects the global economy. In addition, and this is what frightens me, those low interest rates and easy credit are being used by banks and corporations that have learned to increase production and profits through capital investment and technology, but without additional hiring. I fear that this kind of "recovery", specifically improving production and profits with minimal job creation, is what our recovery from future "busts" is going to be like. Our problem, with respect to the Fed and its policies, is that lower interest rates creates output growth without job growth. One of the anomalies in the recent boom and bust, and I think Rajan is correct to call attention to this, is that the boom was an inflation of a particular kind of asset: houses. But houses are not a normal investment asset in at least two ways: (1) We live in our houses, so that "investment" is sticky in the sense that we often will not want to sell when the market tells us that it's wise to do so. (2) With other investment asset there is a mechanism, vehicle, or instrument which can be used to "short" the asset, and that has the effect of limiting inflation and asset bubbles. But, selling short on housing stock is not easy to do. Rajan does describe what needs to be done (to the global financial system, not to education), but he is not optimistic that such reforms will happen. These changes all require sacrifice in the short term, and perhaps even in the long term. Since we, especially in the U.S., have a political system that responds best to immediate wishes of political players (voters, lobbyists, special interest groups, etc), it's not likely that we'll make these changes. But, even if that were possible, we in the U.S. or our political system is not likely to make sacrifices for the benefit of others in the *global* system. It's a bit of a law of the commons and prisoner's dilemma problem. We're going to take as much as we can get until the last blade of grass in the common pasture is gone, because we can't count on others to match our own sacrifices, even if we were far-sighted enough to make those sacrifices. We may just have to accept the fact that our financial and political systems, taken together, are designed to produce high risk, instability, and boom-bust cycles. That's not a happy conclusion. But, perhaps it's just the way our system works. Rajan at least does us the service of showing this rather clearly. Rajan's final hope is that multi-lateral, financial organizations such the IMF and the World Bank should take an active role in influencing countries and the domestic financial systems to make the needed sacrifices, to be more far-sighted, and to act more responsibly. That seems, to me, to be a bit of a "hail mary" pass and a low probability option. I believe that we can expect more of the shocks produced by the fault lines that Rajan describes. 04/14/2011 .. vim:ft=rst:fo+=a: